[Note: If the reader has taken up reading this blog
with this posting, he/she is helped by knowing that this posting is the next
one in a series of postings. The series begins with the posting, “The Natural
Rights’ View of Morality” (February 25, 2020, https://gravitascivics.blogspot.com/2020/02/the-natural-rights-view-of-morality.html). Overall, the
series addresses how the study of political science has affected the civics
curriculum of the nation’s secondary schools.]
To this
point, this blog has reviewed what the political world looks like through the
natural rights perspective. As far as a
theoretical view, the political systems model was central for political
scientists during the decades of the mid twentieth century. Shortly, this blog proceeds with an
overview of the methodology this approach promoted and how those methods
reflected the general adoption of an approach known as behaviorism.[1]
This bias has further influenced the portrayal of government in
American civics courses. That is, it reflects
the market orientation of how Americans have come to see governance and
politics. As described so far, the
political system has multiple parts which interact in order to provide
governmental services. These services
are distributed through a competitive process.
Those who gain the benefits derived from those services do so
because they can exert more power than others.
Educators who instruct students about this process, therefore, are
teaching their students about the exercises of power. Unfortunately, this effect does not extend to
highlight this currency; it is assumed without giving its proper due.
So, the language they use
might not be so blunt, but that is what they are teaching. One can ask, what is power in this social
sense? The definition used here is: power is the ability of a person or a group,
A, to get a person or a group, B, to do something B would not do otherwise.[2]
For example, if one, in an
agitated way, walks into a room, sees another person sitting comfortably on a
lounge chair and yells, “Get up,” and that person stands, that is an incident
of power if one assumption is true. The assumption
is that the other person was not about to stand up on his/her own accord to,
say, get a cup of coffee. That is, that
B was content to continue his/her rest.
This silly example is
important because it illustrates how potentially difficult it is to measure
power – only the lounging person knows what is going on in his/her mind and
what he/she wants to do or is about to do.
At its base then, this business of analyzing politics has a bit
indetermination to it, but that does not seem to humble those who conduct much
of what is called behavioral studies – more on this below.
With a definition in hand,
a further step in conceptualizing power is to look at a categorizing scheme
that identifies types of power. John R.
P. French and Bertram H. Raven identify five types based on the motivation that
someone would have to do something he or she would not want to do otherwise –
that is, the mental states that would lead one to yield to the wishes of
someone else.
This is bit ironic since
behavioral studies claims to stand clear of such mental content – after all,
they claim what is studied is what people do, not what they think and feel. But when one wants to wield power, costs are
involved and if certain strategies are geared to take advantage of what people
are apt to acquiesce to, then one has to speculate as to motivations on the
part of the governed or ruled.
So, there are mental
perceptions or expectations of coercion, reward, legitimacy, expertise, or
reference (known, in turn, as coercive power, reward power, legitimacy power,
expert power, and referent power).[3] This conceptualization is not only applicable
to behavioral studies, but equally apply to either federal theory based-studies
or the studies based on other constructs – power is that central to politics
and political behavior. It is the
currency of politics.
For purposes here, this
account reduces power to three types: avoidance of punishment, seeking reward,
and a sense of duty. One should
consider, when utilizing the systems model, there are winners and losers and
this, in turn, creates issues. No matter
how small in dimension a political engagement happens to be, those who are
engaged in it are participating in a process of competition. They conduct these competitive activities in
the context of a system, a conglomeration of parts and actors that to some
large degree, is organized and is intra-active.
There are actors who are in
positions to make distributive decisions and there are actors who are vying for
sought after gains in the form of policies, waivers, or payouts. In the vying for gains (desired outputs), the
engaged actors can very well hold and promote competing political values and
aims in the form of the preferred policies they are seeking.
Often, these actors,
whether in positions of authority or not (some might enjoy highly influential
positions without holding formal government office), hold a position of a
relative level of power to influence or to make decisions that revolve around
the differences between competing values and preferences. This exercise in power usually reflects
negotiating among the various interests the “players” in a competition might
have. The decision can be not to decide,
to decide in favor of one or a combination of interests, or to compromise on a
policy.
The exercise of power
determines which way it goes. In the
natural rights view, each participant is only concerned with extending that
participant’s interest to the greatest extent possible at the least cost
possible. For better or worse, this is
how the system formulates “consensus” and arrives at a policy decision.
Players are apt to exercise
power in all three forms. It metes out
rewards and punishments and it also solicits a sense of duty and
obligation. Therefore, central to this
whole process are the authoritative decisions that determine whose values will
be honored – catered to – and whose will not.
In addition, a study of
this process (be it by decision-makers, competitors, or academics) entertains
questions about how legitimacy is maintained even among the “losers” of a
political competition. After all, there
is always tomorrow, and the system needs to maintain its players playing by the
rules – rules that need to be of benefit to all.
While this whole process
refers to the organizational workings of groups and government, the systems
approach focuses on the behavior of individuals within that structure who act
from motivations of self-interest.
Obviously, irrespective of the systems model emphasis on the individual
– basic unit of analysis – any study of politics must account for collectives
such as groups, associations, organizations of varying formalities, and
governing processes.
But the political systems
model, as it has already been emphasized, accommodates political analysis of these
collectives under the demands of individual participants behaving in such a way
as to advance each actor’s own individual interests.[4]
One should remember that
how a person defines his/her self-interest can vary from person to person. A person can want monetary benefits or
reputational accolades or artistic recognition or athletic prowess, etc. But however, one defines it, the systems
approach – much in line with Machiavelli thinking[5] – sees this as the
determining motivator in how he or she behaves politically.
A vivid example at this
point helps. That would be New York
City's legendary Robert Moses, who was the central official determining the
winners of New York’s political scene from the 1930s into the 1960s. An extended quote from an interview with
Moses' biographer, Robert Caro, gives one a taste of what is being described:
[For a highway, bridge, tunnel, park, etc.] Moses gave the
contracts, the legal fees, the insurance premiums, the underwriting fees, and
the jobs to the individuals, corporations, and unions who had the most
political influence. So they all had a
vested interest in seeing that his project was built. Therefore, if the people of a neighborhood,
or their assemblyman or congressman, or a mayor or governor, tried to stop one
of his projects, they would find themselves confronted by immense pressure from
the very system they were a part of. A
huge public work – a bridge or a tunnel or a great highway – is a source of raw
power, if it is used right, and no one ever used power with such ingenuity, and
such ruthlessness, as Robert Moses.[6]
Power is not limited to government. Power is potentially exercised in any social
institution – businesses, churches, schools, medical facilities, legal firms,
etc. – or any individual. Given this fact,
one can begin to understand that politics is ubiquitous. The former popular TV show, The Good Wife,[7] dedicates a lot of its
story lines to the political power plays within a legal firm upon which the
series is based. But examples can also
be seen in everyday life.
During a recent Christmas season, the postal service ran an ad
which depicted a husband and wife trying to decide who was going to tackle
which holiday chore. The wife says she
will go to the mall if the husband takes care of mailing the gifts. The husband immediately says that he will go
to the mall because dealing with postage and the post office is a
nightmare.
He grabs the keys and runs to the car for his trip to the
mall. Just then the postman walks up and
explains to the wife that sending packages is easy. She responds with a wink, “I know.” The postman says, “Oh, you're good.” Power comes in many different guises and
being the recipient or the victim might often go unnoticed.
What the last various postings try to communicate is not how
civics is taught. Future postings will
address that. What they to do try is to
communicate a view of politics that has served as an overall understanding of
politics that civics educators, including textbook authors, have brought to the
task of planning and implementing their curricular ideas. How these images have been interpreted needs
to be reviewed and will serve as topics of future postings.
[1] This writer
has also seen this term referred to as behavioralism. Apparently, the term behaviorism refers to
the analysis of behavior in psychology, while behavioralism is a term used in
political science designating the study of political behavior. Both terms are used here interchangeably.
[2] Andre Munro, “Robert A. Dahl:
American Political Scientist and Educator,” Encyclopaedia Britannica,
February 1, 2020, accessed February 12, 2020. https://www.britannica.com/biography/Robert-A-Dahl .
[3] Coercive power occurs when a person does something to avoid
a punishment; reward power occurs when a person does something to gain a
reward; legitimacy power occurs when a person does something out of a sense of
duty; expert power occurs when a person does something because he/she is told
to by a person who he or she believes to have some expertise, such as a doctor
or lawyer; and referent power occurs when someone does something to be
associated with someone, group and/or something.
[4] To be clear, a
lot of the analysis might very well study group dynamics. The point is that even with this level of
analysis, the basic assumption is that each participating actor will strive to
advance his/her self-interest.
[5] See posting, “Foundations of the Natural Rights
View,” March 10, 2020, accessed March 19, 2020, https://gravitascivics.blogspot.com/2020/03/foundations-of-natural-rights-view.html .
[6] Ric Burns and James Sanders, New York: An Illustrated History (New York, NY: Alfred A. Knopf, 1999), 462.
[7] Robert King
and Michell King (creators and producers), The Good Wife, CBS (a
television series), 2009.
No comments:
Post a Comment