In a perhaps tortured posting, “Is
That a Bubbling Noise?,”[1] this
blogger attempted to present an overall view of economic motivations as they
relate to downward trends in a national economy. Brave readers can look up that effort (use
the URL in the citation) and work their way through that text. This current posting will simplify things by
making a related point.
That earlier effort relied on the work
of Richard Posner[2]
as does this one. Here, he, in turn,
relies on John Maynard Keynes. Citing
that economist’s book, The General Theory, Posner points out that there
are two economic options people have when they act economically. They can consume or they can save. For most such actions, that means people
spend or save their money.
Further, Keynes identifies motivations
or concerns for each option. In terms of
consuming, a person might seek enjoyment, generosity, shortsightedness, ostentation,
extravagance, and/or they might simply miscalculate. As for saving, there is a desire or concern for
precaution, calculation, independence, foresight, improvement, enterprise,
independence, and/or pride or avarice.
Surely, readers have at one time, or another, felt each of these motivations
or inclinations.
They
can reflect or recall how they behaved at such times. If money was involved, did they consume or
did they save? Ideally, when should one
consume (which this blogger will call spend or spending) and when should one
save? Perhaps if one generalizes and thinks
aggregately, the question becomes: when
should people spend and when should they save?
Well, Posner states, for the good of the economy, they should save in
times of prosperity – the good times – and spend during times of recession –
the bad times.
Spending
during times of recession helps by increasing economic activity. Saving during times of prosperity helps put at
bay inflationary forces. But that’s not
how they behave. By placing oneself in
one or the other condition, minimal reflection tells one why counter behaviors
prevail.
During
good times, people are apt to have secure employment, enjoy higher levels of
confidence, and more apt to see little risk in indulging or satisfying material
or experiential desires. Of course, the
opposite exists during the bad times when confidence is likely to be challenged
and risks are augmented, at least psychologically if not in reality.
While
the actual economics of these trends and their cyclical character can be quite
complex for civics students in secondary schools, this broad explanation of
spending and saving can be readily understood so that they can at least
appreciate the counterintuitive nature of these factors.
And
included in those factors is that their individual behavior will not tip the national
scale one way or another; they are just one among hundreds of millions of
people. This is important because
students need to consider how people, not individuals, decide these questions
and decide what their behaviors will be.
It
also introduces the need for governmental interference with how the economy
will behave. How? By governments providing counter incentives –
e.g., by manipulating interest rates so that people spend less in inflationary
times and spend more in recessionary times.
But in doing so, government policy defies pure laissez faire economics
or small government politics. Posner,
who in the past was considered a conservative (small government advocate),
questions maintaining limited government responses to economic challenges.
He
writes, for example, in response to such economic nightmares as the 2008 recession
(which he calls a depression) the following:
And
it was a failure of government and of the economics profession rather than of
business, as business foresight is rationally truncated …
In sum, rational maximization by
businessmen and consumers, all pursuing their self-interest more or less intelligently
within a framework of property and contract rights, can set the stage for an
economic catastrophe. There is no need
to bring cognitive quirks, emotional forces, or character flaws into the causal
analysis. This is important both in
simplifying analysis and in avoiding a search, likely to be futile, for means
by which government can alter the mentality or character of businessmen and
consumers.[3]
And these realities further spelled the doom of
how Americans viewed governance and politics.
Up until the Great Depression of the 1930s, the parochial/traditional
federalist view dominated in how Americans understood those concerns. In the minds of most Americans, America was a
rural, agricultural society.
Then, after the depression, came World War II
with huge central government expenditures which brought an end to the
depression and undermined how Americans had understood their government and the
politics it practiced. More
specifically, that war brought to an end the unrealistic notion that America
was a society of small, local communities.
It became obvious that any such view was
doomed. Parochial/traditional construct over-relied
on local governance to meet the governmental and the economic needs of the
population and almost overnight it was considered old- fashioned and inadequate. Its basic tenets were developed during the
colonial period and held up relatively strongly regarding the nation’s economic
realities until the Great Depression.
Yes, that was true to lesser degrees as the
years progressed, and the economy became more and more national and then global. Surely, the events of the Great Depression
and even of World War II made that obvious.
In its end, it became not only dysfunctional but dangerous vis-à-vis
the nation’s ability to survive or maintain its health.
Today, that view is totally inadequate and what
took its place, the natural rights view, falls short as the Posner quote
indicates. The natural rights approach
lends itself to laissez faire thinking, limiting the role of government to
basically police powers. Posner, by just
looking at the basic behaviors of spending and saving, demonstrates how
inadequate natural rights thinking is. While
that view has not prevented an active governmental role in the economy, it has
undermined that role’s legitimacy.
So, that leaves the American people with a
challenge. How can they retain (in some
cases reestablish) the cooperative, collaborative, and communal qualities of
federalism, but adopt a view that realistically accommodates the economic world
that exists today? This blog’s proposal
is for the nation to adopt what it calls liberated federalism. The blog’s purpose has, to date, been to
offer an overall rationale that supports that construct. And that will continue to be its aim.
[1] Robert Gutierrez, “Is that a Bubbling Noise?,” a
posting, Gravitas: A Voice for Civics,
a blog, September 24, 2019, accessed January 6, 2024, URL: https://gravitascivics.blogspot.com/2019_09_22_archive.html.
[2] Richard A. Posner, A Failure of Capitalism: The Crisis of '08
and the Descent into Depression
(Cambridge, MA: Harvard University
Press, 2009).
[3] Ibid., 111-112.
No comments:
Post a Comment