With the a new year upon us in a
few days, I thought it would be a good time to write about one of the
basic social relationships with which all nations – for that
matter, all social collectives – must deal. According to Marxian
thought, this relationship is the main one that societies must
handle. That is the one between both a nation's wealth creation and
distribution and the rest of its institutions; i. e., the function an
economy plays in determining how the nation goes about its
“business.”
I don't believe any blog needs to
convince you that the role of the economy is central to the concerns
of a nation. Our media gives this aspect of national life sufficient
coverage to satisfy the demands of its readers and viewers to stay
informed over the ins and outs of the world of businesses and job
markets, investments and bankruptcies, savings rates and consumption
rates, etc. We seem to be constantly concerned about whether the
economy is growing toward a state of prosperity or whether it is
mired in a sluggish recovery as it is now. At times, we have been in
prolonged periods of downturns in varying degrees of recession and
even depression. We are presently justifiably worried that pending
tax raises will snuff out our anemic climb out of the dismal
conditions that the 2008 crisis triggered.
Nobel prize winning economist,
Joseph E. Stiglitz,1
points out that, on a worldwide basis, governments are not doing what
we should expect them to do when it comes to economic policy. He
explains that we should expect them to put in place those policies
that stabilize economic conditions. Yet, governments have allowed
destabilizing levels of unemployment and underemployment to persist.
By doing so, their polices (or lack of policies) have allowed
under-utilization of resources – specifically labor resources –
while, at the same time, sacrificing our commitment to fairness. In
our nation, the interests of the 99 % have been advanced by
their advocates claiming that, one, markets are not working
correctly, two, markets are not efficient, and three, the political
systems are not correcting the conditions that cause the markets to
be dysfunctional. After all, under traditional market dictum,
markets are supposed to be stable, but the crisis of 2008 amply
demonstrated that they are not. For example, reviews of the behavior
of bankers, the main culprits in the financial collapse, from
commentators from both the left and right, have indicated that they
behaved according to rational incentives – what market theory calls
for. Given the inability of the markets to self-correct in the
months leading to the debacle of '08, that would indicate that there
were, and some fear still are, basic problems with the purity of
related markets, such as the market for real estate.
Dysfunctional markets lead to
conditions that defy basic economic laws such as demand equals
supply. As wealth and income are skewed to certain upper segments of
the population, there are huge levels of unmet needs. This is due to
significant unemployment which in turn becomes a major cause for
inequality. GDP might go up, but standards of living erode and that
is the high price of extreme inequality. Why? Because the
conditions that lead to less stability in our markets transform
markets into becoming less efficient and, ultimately, this leads to
less than optimal growth in the economy. As a result, all of these
negative conditions come about and, by the way, we place our
democracy in peril.
Dangers to our democracy can have
many origins, but of basic concern here is what significant levels of
inequality can lead to: a lack of legitimacy. Citizens, under
whatever system of government or whatever set of governing principles
is employed, must feel that certain standards of fairness are
maintained. But when there is a large disconnect between the
compensation some receive and the contribution to the society or
economy those individuals provide, then the fairness standard is
strained. This was the case when the economy imploded in '08. When
we hear that bankers received large amounts of compensation in the
form of salaries and bonuses despite the fact that the banks these
individuals work for lost great amounts of money, the entire set of
assumptions regarding how efficient the market for executive talent
is is seriously questioned. We see and understand that the misdeeds
that the culprits of 2008 perpetrated on the rest of us have gone
mostly unaccounted for and this fact can be the basis for a lack of
legitimacy in the system itself.
From the federalist perspective,
the above conditions have several points that are disturbing. Most
basic is that skewed wealth and income which we have experienced in
the last decades are in itself troubling. Only the most naïve
cannot see the instability such a condition causes. One does not
have to feel envy to begin questioning the whole purpose of the
system. When a system loses all sense of “we are all in this
together” and instead adopts a feeling that one is only here to
meet the interests of an obscure ideal or, worse, the interests of
some advantaged group, then the rationale for our democratic project
is undermined. And hence, the role of civics should be to not only
describe and explain the economic conditions that are affecting the
democratic quality of the governing system, but also to educate the
youth as to their interests and the means by which to improve the
status of those interests. It should do this if for no other reason
than to help restore a more democratic society. One need not be a
Marxist to see this basic relationship and demand that our
educational efforts address its related concerns in establishing
and/or maintaining a meaningful level of equality.
1The
concerns expressed in this posting inspired from Stiglitz, J. E.
(2012). The price of inequality: How today's divided society
endangers our future. New
York, NY: W. W. Norton and Company.