A Crucial Element of Democracy

This is a blog by Robert Gutierrez ...
While often taken for granted, civics education plays a crucial role in a democracy like ours. This Blog is dedicated to enticing its readers into taking an active role in the formulation of the civics curriculum found in their local schools. In order to do this, the Blog is offering a newer way to look at civics education, a newer construct - liberated federalism or federation theory. Daniel Elazar defines federalism as "the mode of political organization that unites separate polities within an overarching political system by distributing power among general and constituent governments in a manner designed to protect the existence and authority of both." It depends on its citizens acting in certain ways which Elazar calls federalism's processes. Federation theory, as applied to civics curriculum, has a set of aims. They are:
*Teach a view of government as a supra federated institution of society in which collective interests of the commonwealth are protected and advanced.
*Teach the philosophical basis of government's role as guardian of the grand partnership of citizens at both levels of individuals and associations of political and social intercourse.
*Convey the need of government to engender levels of support promoting a general sense of obligation and duty toward agreed upon goals and processes aimed at advancing the common betterment.
*Establish and justify a political morality which includes a process to assess whether that morality meets the needs of changing times while holding true to federalist values.
*Emphasize the integrity of the individual both in terms of liberty and equity in which each citizen is a member of a compacted arrangement and whose role is legally, politically, and socially congruent with the spirit of the Bill of Rights.
*Find a balance between a respect for national expertise and an encouragement of local, unsophisticated participation in policy decision-making and implementation.
Your input, as to the content of this Blog, is encouraged through this Blog directly or the Blog's email address: gravitascivics@gmail.com .
NOTE: This blog has led to the publication of a book. The title of that book is TOWARD A FEDERATED NATION: IMPLEMENTING NATIONAL CIVICS STANDARDS and it is available through Amazon in both ebook and paperback versions.

Friday, January 12, 2024

CONTRACT VS. COMPACT

 

This posting is a short follow up to the last posting, “Spending and Saving.”  In that prior posting, a simple economic factor was pointed out and related to what government’s role should be in the economy.  Here is not a restatement of that relationship, but a further analysis of a point that posting made.  That is, that the construct, parochial/traditional federalism, a dominant view that Americans shared in the years before World War II, was inadequate for the more modern times of American governance and politics.

          In this clarification, the term parochial is central.  To cite Wikipedia, one finds the following:

 

Parochialism is the state of mind whereby one focuses on small sections of an issue rather than considering its wider context. More generally, it consists of being narrow in scope. In that respect, it is a synonym of "provincialism". It may, particularly when used pejoratively, be contrasted to cosmopolitanism.[1] 

 

It is a term this blogger originally was introduced to in his growing up years within the Catholic tradition. 

He went to parochial schools for 13 years.  What little questioning he expressed at the time solicited a sense that parochialism referred to the local church and local concerns – much in line with what Wikipedia states.  What he was to learn and appreciate was how central this idea was to American culture until, as the last posting pointed out, the realities of a national and now global economy made this provincialism untenable.

          It particularly applies to views of governance and politics in the US, since for various reasons, localism was held to be central to the American experience.  The federalism that grew in the US was originally based on the local settlements that sprung up on the eastern seacoast of the North American landmass.  Each was the product of settlers joining together and formulating a polity based on what was considered a sacred agreement.  The word, compacts, applies to these agreements.

          More specifically, as Daniel Elazar explains, these agreements were a type of compact, that being covenants.[2]  In that they resembled Judeo tradition, covenants established a union in which whatever members did, they were part of that union.  The signees of the agreement called on God to witness the agreement which solemnized it. 

As the American people became a bit more secular – to a degree the product of the Enlightenment – this element was put aside, making the newer agreements straightforward compacts. A comparison that illustrates this turn is that the Declaration of Independence (1776) is a covenant, and the US Constitution (1787) is simply a compact.  In both cases, the purpose was to hold those agreements in solemnity.

The distinctions one can make between or among the founding documents (including, for example, state constitutions) and the terms one uses to classify them have consequences.  And to illustrate, a legal matter comes to mind.  To further distinguish what is being described in this posting, it introduces yet another term, that being contract.  Here, a historical turn – an unfortunate one – muddles the waters.  And sure enough, the French have a role.  No, French influence is not at odds with fortune, but in terms of constitutional principles, it does have another tradition.

The origins of this difference can be traced to Jean-Jacques Rousseau and how he envisioned the ways and reasons people organized to form polities.  In doing so, they give up some natural rights – the ability to behave as they wish – to practically allow them to live under a set of laws or restrictions.  This language casts a different sense from what the Judeo tradition called for.

With a social contract, one deals with a quid pro quo – something for something (personal rights for societal arrangement).  This stands in distinction to a more communal sense of the Judeo model.  But if applied to the Constitution, it casts that agreement with a more contractual sense and diminishes its compact-al or communal orientation.

On a practical level, for example, with a social contract – the more contractual approach – the courts, usually at the hands of conservative jurists, have elected to interpret the Constitution and laws in a literal fashion, like one interprets a contract.  This is called textualism.  It holds other ways to interpret – such as historically, traditionally, structurally, prudentially, morally or based on precedent – as being illegitimate to some degree. 

In this singular way, one can see how this other view – the natural rights view – has drained, from the American experience, the bonding force of a communal constitutional framework.  The consequences have been numerous and have most recently included the palpable sense of a politically polarized citizenry.  As the last posting concluded, a form of federalism – a compact approach – would benefit the American people by reintroducing a more communal sense – with hopefully less parochialism – to its constitutional view.



[1] See “Parochialism,” Wikipedia (n.d.), accessed January 9, 2024, URL:  Parochialism - Wikipedia.

[2] This blog has repeatedly cited Elazar.  For a more recent citing, see “Compact Theory of the U.S. Constitution,” Center for the Study of Federalism (n.d.), accessed January 9, 2024, URL:  https://encyclopedia.federalism.org/index.php/Compact_Theory_of_the_U.S._Constitution.

Tuesday, January 9, 2024

SPENDING AND SAVING

 

In a perhaps tortured posting, “Is That a Bubbling Noise?,”[1] this blogger attempted to present an overall view of economic motivations as they relate to downward trends in a national economy.  Brave readers can look up that effort (use the URL in the citation) and work their way through that text.  This current posting will simplify things by making a related point.

          That earlier effort relied on the work of Richard Posner[2] as does this one.  Here, he, in turn, relies on John Maynard Keynes.  Citing that economist’s book, The General Theory, Posner points out that there are two economic options people have when they act economically.  They can consume or they can save.  For most such actions, that means people spend or save their money.

          Further, Keynes identifies motivations or concerns for each option.  In terms of consuming, a person might seek enjoyment, generosity, shortsightedness, ostentation, extravagance, and/or they might simply miscalculate.  As for saving, there is a desire or concern for precaution, calculation, independence, foresight, improvement, enterprise, independence, and/or pride or avarice.  Surely, readers have at one time, or another, felt each of these motivations or inclinations.  

They can reflect or recall how they behaved at such times.  If money was involved, did they consume or did they save?  Ideally, when should one consume (which this blogger will call spend or spending) and when should one save?  Perhaps if one generalizes and thinks aggregately, the question becomes:  when should people spend and when should they save?  Well, Posner states, for the good of the economy, they should save in times of prosperity – the good times – and spend during times of recession – the bad times. 

Spending during times of recession helps by increasing economic activity.  Saving during times of prosperity helps put at bay inflationary forces.  But that’s not how they behave.  By placing oneself in one or the other condition, minimal reflection tells one why counter behaviors prevail. 

During good times, people are apt to have secure employment, enjoy higher levels of confidence, and more apt to see little risk in indulging or satisfying material or experiential desires.  Of course, the opposite exists during the bad times when confidence is likely to be challenged and risks are augmented, at least psychologically if not in reality.

While the actual economics of these trends and their cyclical character can be quite complex for civics students in secondary schools, this broad explanation of spending and saving can be readily understood so that they can at least appreciate the counterintuitive nature of these factors. 

And included in those factors is that their individual behavior will not tip the national scale one way or another; they are just one among hundreds of millions of people.  This is important because students need to consider how people, not individuals, decide these questions and decide what their behaviors will be.

It also introduces the need for governmental interference with how the economy will behave.  How?  By governments providing counter incentives – e.g., by manipulating interest rates so that people spend less in inflationary times and spend more in recessionary times.  But in doing so, government policy defies pure laissez faire economics or small government politics.  Posner, who in the past was considered a conservative (small government advocate), questions maintaining limited government responses to economic challenges. 

He writes, for example, in response to such economic nightmares as the 2008 recession (which he calls a depression) the following:

 

And it was a failure of government and of the economics profession rather than of business, as business foresight is rationally truncated …

            In sum, rational maximization by businessmen and consumers, all pursuing their self-interest more or less intelligently within a framework of property and contract rights, can set the stage for an economic catastrophe.  There is no need to bring cognitive quirks, emotional forces, or character flaws into the causal analysis.  This is important both in simplifying analysis and in avoiding a search, likely to be futile, for means by which government can alter the mentality or character of businessmen and consumers.[3]

 

And these realities further spelled the doom of how Americans viewed governance and politics.  Up until the Great Depression of the 1930s, the parochial/traditional federalist view dominated in how Americans understood those concerns.  In the minds of most Americans, America was a rural, agricultural society.

Then, after the depression, came World War II with huge central government expenditures which brought an end to the depression and undermined how Americans had understood their government and the politics it practiced.   More specifically, that war brought to an end the unrealistic notion that America was a society of small, local communities. 

It became obvious that any such view was doomed.  Parochial/traditional construct over-relied on local governance to meet the governmental and the economic needs of the population and almost overnight it was considered old- fashioned and inadequate.  Its basic tenets were developed during the colonial period and held up relatively strongly regarding the nation’s economic realities until the Great Depression. 

Yes, that was true to lesser degrees as the years progressed, and the economy became more and more national and then global.  Surely, the events of the Great Depression and even of World War II made that obvious.  In its end, it became not only dysfunctional but dangerous vis-à-vis the nation’s ability to survive or maintain its health. 

Today, that view is totally inadequate and what took its place, the natural rights view, falls short as the Posner quote indicates.  The natural rights approach lends itself to laissez faire thinking, limiting the role of government to basically police powers.  Posner, by just looking at the basic behaviors of spending and saving, demonstrates how inadequate natural rights thinking is.  While that view has not prevented an active governmental role in the economy, it has undermined that role’s legitimacy.

So, that leaves the American people with a challenge.  How can they retain (in some cases reestablish) the cooperative, collaborative, and communal qualities of federalism, but adopt a view that realistically accommodates the economic world that exists today?  This blog’s proposal is for the nation to adopt what it calls liberated federalism.  The blog’s purpose has, to date, been to offer an overall rationale that supports that construct.  And that will continue to be its aim.



[1] Robert Gutierrez, “Is that a Bubbling Noise?,” a posting, Gravitas:  A Voice for Civics, a blog, September 24, 2019, accessed January 6, 2024, URL: https://gravitascivics.blogspot.com/2019_09_22_archive.html.

[2] Richard A. Posner, A Failure of Capitalism: The Crisis of '08 and the Descent into Depression (Cambridge, MA:  Harvard University Press, 2009).

[3] Ibid., 111-112.